Corruption is one of the
greatest challenges of the contemporary world. It undermines good government, fundamentally distorts public
policy, leads to the misallocation of resources, harms the private sector and
private sector development and particularly hurts the poor. Controlling it is only possible with
the co-operation of a wide range of stakeholders in the integrity system,
including most importantly the state, civil society, and the private sector. [Transparency International] recognizes
the shared responsibility of actors in all the regions for corruption, and its
emphasis is on prevention and on reforming systems, not on exposing individual
cases; TI considers that the movement against corruption is global and
transcends social, political, economic and cultural systems. TI is politically non-partisan; and TI
recognizes that there are strong practical as well as ethical reasons for
containing corruption. (Excerpt
from Transparency International's Mission Statement)
As
national economies around the globe are becoming increasingly linked to one
another and to the ideals of liberal democracy and free-market capitalism, a
discourse of anti-corruption has emerged as one of the newest organizing
schemas of international governance, development and business. There is a moral and ethical assumption
that certain "bad", morally bereft and economically damaging
behaviors constitute "a cancer" and as such should be labeled corrupt
(Wolfenson 1999). Corruption must
be cut out if democracies and free markets around the world are to develop
sustainably (Wescott 1997, Eigen 1999, Stappenhurst and Kpundeh 1999, Robbins
2000). It is chiefly international
development institutions and NGOs within the United States and Europe such as
the World Bank, United States Agency for International Development (USAID),
United Nations Development Program (UNDP), Organization for Economic
Cooperation and Development (OECD) and Transparency International (TI) that
have led the battle cry against corruption.[1] Eradicating corruption, these
institutions propose, will enable a logical progression towards economic growth
through transparency, accountability, efficiency, good governance, an equitable
distribution of wealth and improvement in social welfare, resulting in a
reduction in poverty and the assurance of sustainable development (Eigen 1999b,
Clay 1997, World Bank 2000, de
Magalh‹es 2000, Transparency International 2001), and ultimately, democracy
(Mosley, Harrigan and Toye 1995).
These
institutions promote themselves as the vanguard of anticorruption experts, led
by the World Bank and Transparency International. By standardizing definitions of corruption and identifying
specific strategies for Òcombating corruptionÓ (Eigen 1999b) these institutions
are concurrently inferring that they themselves are uncorrupt. Defining and identifying function as
acts of demarcation and distancing.
Unlike standard development knowledge claims, this expertise is not
scientific in nature. Stemming
from a rationality reflected in the neoliberal economic policies expected to
stymie corruption, these experts take a larger step toward claims of moral and
ethical clarity. Corruption is not
only illegal, but it is immoral.
Corruption reflects a condition of underdevelopment, not scientifically,
but morally, ethically, and economically.
It is the next level in the demarcation between underdevelopment and
development, i.e. modernity. The
morality of anti-corruption has become an important justification for invasive
neoliberal economic policies and international institutional intervention.
Peter Eigen, the founder and chairman of Transparency
International, proposes Òthree key pillarsÓ of the global effort to reduce
corruption: private business, government and civil society (Eigen 1999b). While each pillar is responsible to
address the unwieldy nature of corruption in different ways, Eigen and others
suggest that it is civil society that has the widest public support and
strongest moral position from which to take on corruption (Eigen 1999a, Eigen
1999b, Westcott 1997). The
anti-corruption institutions characterize civil society as the sector driven by
the greatest level of altruism and purity, maintaining the authentic qualities
of democracy inherent to making choices based on the greater good to
society. Authenticity and purity
are juxtaposed to the essential character of corruption. A variety of actors, such as
international finance and development institutions as well as NGOs, utilize
these concepts to legitimate their own behavior, as well as to create images of
themselves and/or others that cloud the true issues of corruption inherent to
both the formal and informal realms in Panama. This promotes a romanticized notion of NGOs as the moral
watchdogs in developing nations.
In
every nation of the world, the development of practices now labeled as
nepotism, bribery, donning favors, extortion, fraud, trafficking and
embezzlement, have their own particular histories that impact the form these
practices take in each national societal setting. The chairman of TI, Eigen acknowledges that there is
cultural relativity involved in what he terms corrupt.
(W)hat may be described as
corruption, can vary from one society to another. This is particularly true with practices surrounding gifts,
legitimate and illegitimate hospitality and the use of personal
connections. There is no one line
between culturally and socially accepted behavior on the one hand and nepotism
and corruption on the other and each society has to draw this for itself. (Eigen 1999a)
As Eigen infers,
practices that exist in an unofficial sphere are not without rules or
legitimization, within their immediate context. Agreements that may be judicially illegitimate are not
necessarily socially or politically illegitimate. Quite to the contrary.
Generally, a nationÕs populace, or a particular segment of the
population is well aware of how the system works and how to work the system to their own benefit. As Robbins points out,
"(corruption) is not the absence of rules but the presence of alternative
norms" (Robbins 2000: 426).
Often the official system of Òanti-corruption" is actually the
less-practiced alternative, the cover story for the informal system of exchange
and power brokering that forms the basis for well-known standardized rules and
norms. Economic historian Alan
Fowler calls the coexistence of formal and informal rules and practices Òthe
living systemÓ (Fowler 1991: 54).
What is termed corrupt by one faction is the normalized system of
another faction, for whom transparent practices are masks, the alternative to
familiar and well-developed systems and networks of favors and payments. The World Bank makes a similar point by writing, "In some of
these countries high levels of corruption may be a stable equilibrium, with political
elites, bureaucratic functionaries, entrepreneurs, and ordinary people all
bound by its rules" (World Bank 2002).
In
Panama, there is a long tradition of corrupt practices[2],
locally termed juega vivo,
functioning at all levels of society in a variety of contexts[3]. Corruption in Panama can only be
understood within an international context, as PanamaÕs history and traditions
are strongly linked to its history as a service economy and the corresponding
influence and relations with international economic, political and social
forces, particularly those of the United States. Not only is corruption associated with PanamaÕs formal
service-based economy, but with illegal arms trading, drug trade and money laundering,
all vital facets of PanamaÕs informal economy. These rules and norms are woven into the societal fabric,
the expectations and rituals of day to day life. Informal exchange systems, particularly those at a national,
regional or local scale, often necessitate intimate personal knowledge of the
various people involved in the exchange - what are someone's likes and
dislikes, what and how much they produce, to whom they are related and where
they went to school. It is a very
personal system of networking and exchange that solidifies social relations[4].
The
environmental arena, associated as it is with the reversion of the Panama
Canal, with USAID and other large international governmental and
nongovernmental organizations, is a new forum for the replication and morphing
of established practices and traditions at the level of elite and middle
class. At the same time, the newly
developing environmental arena has created the possibility for new actors, such
as rural mestizo and indigenous farmers and the local leadership to enter into
the practices of corruption, both overtly and covertly.
In
this chapter, I question why corruption has become such an important discourse
at this particular moment in time.
What is accomplished through the extension of a morally universal
anti-corruption standard by particular institutions of the industrialized
North? What are the roles of
corruption and the tradition of juega vivo in Panama, and what are its connections with the expansion of
democratic and neoliberal economic agendas?
I
provide an overview of some of the history and issues of corruption particular
to Panama, often referred to as juega vivo. I exemplify the ways in
which all classes adopt their own behavior to fit within the relations of power
and make new adaptations according to the opportunities presented by the
resources available from environmental conservation projects.
Through the examination of the structural position of environmental NGOs to the overall system of power, I demonstrate that rather than curbing corruption, environmental NGOs are a key site for the growth and extension of normalized practices of corruption in Panama at all class levels.
[1] Throughout this chapter when I refer to the institutions promoting an anti-corruption discourse, I am referring to these organizations first and foremost.
[2] I use the terms corruption and corrupt practices throughout this chapter. In doing so, I am referring to practices that the institutions listed above suggest as corrupt rather than as a description of practices that are inherently morally or ethically corrupt.
[3]There is a danger in over-emphasizing the ÒtraditionalÓ and relativized nature of PanamaÕs informal networks and the unique way that corruption has become a major thread in the national culture. It is counterproductive to encourage romantic notions of local practice as natural, good, pure or authentic. Once again, it is concentrating on what is produced by a confluence of actors and their actions that keeps this romanticization at bay. In fact, these traditions are in part responsible for the extreme income disparity between rich and poor in Panama. The exclusive sharing of wealth and power among elite and to a lesser degree, the middle class, has by and large prevented lower urban and rural populations from entering into the political and economic arena with them. Those who have the power to grant access to resources, to give contracts, reduce taxes, help put someone else in a position of power, turn a blind eye on unsanctioned activities etc., are one part of this equation. Those who have something valuable to give in exchange are another part of the equation. Often the poorest sector of the population, which has little monetary or social capital with which to negotiate deals, is unable to partake and benefit from high-level informal systems of exchange and gift giving. Favors and the acquisition of jobs and contracts tend to circulate among the elite upper class, reinforcing income disparity and limiting the economic advancement of the lower classes.
[4] While in Panama, I met with a Panamanian woman working at the American Embassy. Initially her job had been to keep track of Panamanian legislation as well as formal agreements made with the United States. But a year earlier her job shifted and she was now responsible for introducing Americans politicians and business people working with the Embassy to the appropriate people in Panama. With a smile on her face, she told me that in order to connect someone to the correct important people, the most vital information for her to keep track of was Òwho was sleeping with whom in PanamaÓ. With this thinly veiled joke, she was telling me that deals in Panama are made in a way that has little or nothing to do with formal agreements. Linking people to the appropriate social and political connections is based on her intimate knowledge of the lives of the elite class.